Difference between revisions of "Economic impact of security measures"

From Securipedia
Jump to navigation Jump to search
 
(67 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
[[Category:Economic]][[Category:Safety]][[Category:Measure]]
=Economic impact of security measures=
 
With the help of security measures it is possible to eliminate the risk of a terrorist or criminal event, or at least reduce the risk. [[Measure|Security measures]], however, also generate economic impact, here referred to as the '''economic impact of security measures'''. This includes the costs of securing a specific urban object, but also the costs and benefits regarding the secondary impact of security measures.
 
   
 
With the help of security measures it is possible to eliminate the risk of a terrorist or criminal event, or at least reduce the risk. [[Measure|Security measures]], however, also generate [[Economic impact|economic impact]], here referred to as the '''economic impact of security measures'''. This includes the costs of securing a specific urban object, but also the costs and benefits regarding the secondary impact of security measures.
== The Relevance for Urban Planners ==
 
The cost of crime and terrorism mitigation (with the help of security measures) contains the relatively straightforward direct expenditures on capital equipment and operational costs. However, in addition to thease operational costs, security measures generate various types of secondary effects that have a lasting impact on the economy of an urban environment. Hence it is relevant for urban planners to have insight in the economic side effects of taken security measures.
 
   
==Types of impact==
+
== Description ==
  +
Security measures intend to increase the level of security, deterring a security event and/or at least mitigating the negative [[Economic impact of security threats| socio-economic impact of crime and terrorism]]. There are, however, costs involved with the improvement of urban security, also referred to as the "Costs of Mitigation"<ref>Rose, A & S. Chatterjee (2011): Benefits and Costs of Counter-Terrorism Security Measures in Urban Areas. Research sponsor: Department of Homeland Security. p. 6-7</ref>. These costs contain, first of all, [[Primary economic impact|direct investments]] in equipment, training and operational costs by private agents, companies/developers and the public authorities, exacting [[Economic impact|economic cost/impact]]. Secondly, the mitigation effort generates various types of [[Secondary economic impact|secondary effects]], for example, in terms of delays (think of airport security), inconveniences (e.g. due to access control), and diffusions in the business environment, creating an unintended fear factor.
Although largely similar, there are differences in the economic effects of (see '''clickable map'''):
 
   
  +
Whether these primary and secondary costs are making sense from an economic point of view depends on many factors, and can be answered by two distinct sets of questions:
<imagemap>
 
  +
# Are the envisioned security measures cost effective from a socio-economic point of view, or are there better alternatives?
Image:Economic_impact_of_security_measures.png|330 px
 
  +
# Which specific agents (individuals, companies, sectors, authorities) are affected by the security measures and to which extend? How do the envisioned measures adjust the behaviour of these agents, and of course the [[The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|behaviour of criminals/terrorists]]?
   
  +
The most cost-effective security prevention strategies do not just take the impact on crime and/or terrorism into account, but also the geographical, cultural, socio-economic and social characteristics. According to Feins ''et al.'' (1997)<ref>Feins, J.D., J.C. Epstein & R. Widom (1997): Solving Crime Problems in Residential Neigborhoods: Comprehensive Changes in Design, Management, and Use. U.S. Department of Justice. Office of Justice Programs. National Institute of Justice.</ref> these characteristics are in general so unique and complex, that the selection of security measures should always involve a coalition of local stakeholders and objective experts. Moreover, the attempt to replicate a successful security strategy will most likely also fail according to professor Paul Ekblom (2008)<ref>Ekblom, P. (2008): The 5Is framework: a practical tool for transfer and sharing of crime prevention and community safety knowledge. Design Against Crime Research Centre.</ref> as preventive action is very "context-dependent" for its success<ref>"It relies on practitioners intelligently following a process of identifying and solving a given crime problem, and customising generic preventive principles to activate specific causal mechanisms of prevention which fit the current context."Source: Ekblom, P. (2008): The 5Is framework: a practical tool for transfer and sharing of crime prevention and community safety knowledge. Design Against Crime Research Centre.</ref>.
rect 1 97 214 189 [[Economic impact of security measures]]
 
rect 284 2 494 95 [[ Economic effects of anti-crime security measures| Economic effects of anti-crime security measures]]
 
rect 282 178 494 271 [[Economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures|Economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures]]
 
   
  +
== The role of economic tools==
desc bottom-left
 
  +
[[Economic tools]] such as the [[social cost-benefit analysis]] (first question) and [[Economic Impact Study|economic impact study]] (second question) can help the decision makers to answer the above mentioned questions, and to prevent wasteful expenditures on security (of course in collaboration with insights from criminology, sociology, etc.).The basic starting point of any cost-benefit analysis of security measures is to estimate the costs. This is, however, much more complex than it might seem at first sight, since the total cost of security does not just contain the upfront investment costs in security equipment, training, management, etc., but also much less tangible effects like the value of time, effects on system functionality (e.g. logistic systems), macro-economic effects (on GDP), the [[Opportunity cost|opportunity cost]] of public spendings on security, and consumer preferences/behaviour (e.g. the dislike of very present security measures like screening of personal belongings). As a result, different cost estimates of security measures are not always in agreement with results strongly depending on the definition of costs and the methods used.
</imagemap>
 
   
  +
Estimation of the expected benefits of security measures is the second step. These benefits basically depend on the magnitude of the risk of a security threat (crime and terrorism), and the reduction in these expected losses (in economic terms). Hence, if the risk of a certain event is low, the potential benefits of improved security will also be low, no matter how expensive this measure is. Or, the other way around: If a certain risk is very high, even a small risk reduction will generate substantial benefits. Since both the magnitudes of risks and the impact of security measures are difficult to estimate, it can be helpful to think in terms of how much a certain security measure should reduce the risk of a security threat to be cost-effective. For example, if surveillance measures in a particular urban area cost 10 million euro per year, and the expected losses of crime and terrorism in that area are 100 million euro per year, a 10 percent reduction in risk would justify the cost of this surveillance measure (assuming it is realised by this particular security option, and not different measures or circumstances). To do this, economists use different sets of assumptions and parameters about criminal and terrorist behaviour, crime statistics, risk assumptions, etc. enabling them to analyse the cost-effectiveness of a single or multiple security measures<ref>In practice, serious targets like transportation hubs or utility objects are hardly ever protected by a single security measure. See e.g., Jackson ''et al'' (2012): Efficient Aviation Security. Strengthening the Analytic Foundation for Making Air Transportation Security Decisions. Rand Homeland Security and Defense Center, p.54.</ref>.
==Related subjects==
 
The economic impact of security measures are closely related to:
 
#The [[Economic impact of security threats|economic impact of security threats (crime & terrorism)]]
 
#The [[The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|economics of criminal & terrorist behaviour]]
 
   
 
==Types of impact of security measures==
Other related subjects are illustrated in the '''clickable map''' below:
 
 
Although largely similar, there are differences in the economic effects of (see also clickable map below):
 
* [[Economic effects of anti-crime security measures|economic effects of anti-crime security measures]]
 
* [[Economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures|economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures]]
   
 
<imagemap>
Crime and terrorism are a major part of every European society. The types of costs and economic effects of crime and terrorism are widely varried and will be referred to as '''economic impact of security threats'''.
 
  +
Image:Security_measures_crime_&_terrorism.jpg| 500px
   
 
rect 0 2 317 178 [[Economic effects of anti-crime security measures]]
== The Relevance for Urban Planners ==
 
 
rect 427 0 743 178 [[Economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures]]
* The [[comprises::Economic effects of crime|costs and effects of crime]] touch just about everyone to some degree. The ultimate cost of crime is the loss of life, but other major costs to victims of crime include medical costs, property losses, and loss of income.
 
   
 
desc bottom-left
* After a big terrorist event, one can read frequently about the economic damage of the event on the local economy such as after the London Bombings in 2005 or the September 11 attacks in New York. Due to the significant [[comprises::Economic effects of terrorism|costs and effects of terrorism]], knowledge about this theme is of major relevance for any urban planner.
 
 
</imagemap>
 
Put differently, the economic impact of security threats (crime & terrorism) can be significant and explains why economists and related scholars increasingly analyzed the economic impact of crime and terrorism.
 
 
== Groups of economic impact of security threats==
 
According to Krugman (2004)<ref name="ftn13"> Krugman, P. (2004). ''The Nexus of Terrorism & WMDs: Developing a Consensus''. Princeton University.</ref> (a Nobel Prize-winning economist), the economic impact of terrorism is similar to the economic impact of crime, and can be divided into three groups:
 
# The direct economic impact performed by criminal and terrorist acts on the urban object/environment (buildings and infrastructure destroyed, productive lives ended).
 
# The indirect economic impact (on the urban environment) such as effects on tourism, investments, consumption, trade, etc.).
 
# Budget effects of preventive security measures against crime and terrorism such as money spent on national defense, airport security, and the police, in an attempt to prevent or forestall future criminal and terrorist events.
 
 
It is important to realise for urban planners that crime and terrorism do not only lead to direct physical costs and preventive measures, but also generate less tangible costs that are not easily or precisely identified, but can be of major importance for the local economy. This will be further explained on the specific pages (see above).
 
   
 
==Related subjects==
 
==Related subjects==
  +
*[[Economic|Economic main page]]
The economic impact of security threats are closely related to:
 
* [[belongs to::Economic impact]]
+
* [[Economic impact]]
  +
**[[Economic impact of urban planning]]
* The [[is synonymous to::economic effects of security measures]]
 
 
**[[Economic impact of security threats]]
* The [[is synonymous to::The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|economics of terrorist and criminal behaviour]]
 
 
**Economic impact of security measures:
  +
***[[Economic effects of anti-crime security measures]]
  +
***[[Economic effects of anti-terrorism security measures]]
 
**[[The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|Economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour]]
  +
*[[Economic tools]]
  +
*[[Economic output]]
   
  +
{{references}}
 
 
= MAP =
 
<websiteFrame>
 
website=http://securipedia.eu/cool/index.php?wiki=securipedia.eu&concept=Economic_impact_of_security_measures
 
height=1023
 
width=100%
 
border=0
 
scroll=auto
 
align=middle
 
</websiteFrame>
 
 
<headertabs/>
 
[[Category:Economic]][[Category:Safety]][[Category:Measure]]
 

Latest revision as of 00:05, 20 January 2018


With the help of security measures it is possible to eliminate the risk of a terrorist or criminal event, or at least reduce the risk. Security measures, however, also generate economic impact, here referred to as the economic impact of security measures. This includes the costs of securing a specific urban object, but also the costs and benefits regarding the secondary impact of security measures.

Description

Security measures intend to increase the level of security, deterring a security event and/or at least mitigating the negative socio-economic impact of crime and terrorism. There are, however, costs involved with the improvement of urban security, also referred to as the "Costs of Mitigation"[1]. These costs contain, first of all, direct investments in equipment, training and operational costs by private agents, companies/developers and the public authorities, exacting economic cost/impact. Secondly, the mitigation effort generates various types of secondary effects, for example, in terms of delays (think of airport security), inconveniences (e.g. due to access control), and diffusions in the business environment, creating an unintended fear factor.

Whether these primary and secondary costs are making sense from an economic point of view depends on many factors, and can be answered by two distinct sets of questions:

  1. Are the envisioned security measures cost effective from a socio-economic point of view, or are there better alternatives?
  2. Which specific agents (individuals, companies, sectors, authorities) are affected by the security measures and to which extend? How do the envisioned measures adjust the behaviour of these agents, and of course the behaviour of criminals/terrorists?

The most cost-effective security prevention strategies do not just take the impact on crime and/or terrorism into account, but also the geographical, cultural, socio-economic and social characteristics. According to Feins et al. (1997)[2] these characteristics are in general so unique and complex, that the selection of security measures should always involve a coalition of local stakeholders and objective experts. Moreover, the attempt to replicate a successful security strategy will most likely also fail according to professor Paul Ekblom (2008)[3] as preventive action is very "context-dependent" for its success[4].

The role of economic tools

Economic tools such as the social cost-benefit analysis (first question) and economic impact study (second question) can help the decision makers to answer the above mentioned questions, and to prevent wasteful expenditures on security (of course in collaboration with insights from criminology, sociology, etc.).The basic starting point of any cost-benefit analysis of security measures is to estimate the costs. This is, however, much more complex than it might seem at first sight, since the total cost of security does not just contain the upfront investment costs in security equipment, training, management, etc., but also much less tangible effects like the value of time, effects on system functionality (e.g. logistic systems), macro-economic effects (on GDP), the opportunity cost of public spendings on security, and consumer preferences/behaviour (e.g. the dislike of very present security measures like screening of personal belongings). As a result, different cost estimates of security measures are not always in agreement with results strongly depending on the definition of costs and the methods used.

Estimation of the expected benefits of security measures is the second step. These benefits basically depend on the magnitude of the risk of a security threat (crime and terrorism), and the reduction in these expected losses (in economic terms). Hence, if the risk of a certain event is low, the potential benefits of improved security will also be low, no matter how expensive this measure is. Or, the other way around: If a certain risk is very high, even a small risk reduction will generate substantial benefits. Since both the magnitudes of risks and the impact of security measures are difficult to estimate, it can be helpful to think in terms of how much a certain security measure should reduce the risk of a security threat to be cost-effective. For example, if surveillance measures in a particular urban area cost 10 million euro per year, and the expected losses of crime and terrorism in that area are 100 million euro per year, a 10 percent reduction in risk would justify the cost of this surveillance measure (assuming it is realised by this particular security option, and not different measures or circumstances). To do this, economists use different sets of assumptions and parameters about criminal and terrorist behaviour, crime statistics, risk assumptions, etc. enabling them to analyse the cost-effectiveness of a single or multiple security measures[5].

Types of impact of security measures

Although largely similar, there are differences in the economic effects of (see also clickable map below):

Economic effects of anti-crime security measuresEconomic effects of anti-terrorism security measuresSecurity measures crime & terrorism.jpg
About this image

Related subjects

Footnotes and references

  1. Rose, A & S. Chatterjee (2011): Benefits and Costs of Counter-Terrorism Security Measures in Urban Areas. Research sponsor: Department of Homeland Security. p. 6-7
  2. Feins, J.D., J.C. Epstein & R. Widom (1997): Solving Crime Problems in Residential Neigborhoods: Comprehensive Changes in Design, Management, and Use. U.S. Department of Justice. Office of Justice Programs. National Institute of Justice.
  3. Ekblom, P. (2008): The 5Is framework: a practical tool for transfer and sharing of crime prevention and community safety knowledge. Design Against Crime Research Centre.
  4. "It relies on practitioners intelligently following a process of identifying and solving a given crime problem, and customising generic preventive principles to activate specific causal mechanisms of prevention which fit the current context."Source: Ekblom, P. (2008): The 5Is framework: a practical tool for transfer and sharing of crime prevention and community safety knowledge. Design Against Crime Research Centre.
  5. In practice, serious targets like transportation hubs or utility objects are hardly ever protected by a single security measure. See e.g., Jackson et al (2012): Efficient Aviation Security. Strengthening the Analytic Foundation for Making Air Transportation Security Decisions. Rand Homeland Security and Defense Center, p.54.