Difference between revisions of "Social cost-benefit analysis"
(24 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
⚫ | |||
− | = Social cost-benefit analysis = |
||
− | '''Social cost-benefit analysis''' is a systematic and cohesive method to survey all the impacts caused by an urban development project<ref name="ftn84"> In the Netherlands, conducting a social cost- |
+ | [[File:ae.png|25px|right|This is a page providing background in a specific field of expertise]]'''Social cost-benefit analysis''' is a systematic and cohesive [[Economic tools|economic tool]](method) to survey all the impacts caused by an urban development project<ref name="ftn84"> In the Netherlands, conducting a social cost-benefit analysis is mandatory for major infrastructure projects.</ref>. It comprises not just the financial effects (investment costs, direct benefits like tax and fees, et cetera), but all the social effects, like: pollution, safety, indirect (labour) market, legal aspects, et cetera. The main aim of a social cost-benefit analysis is to attach a price to as many effects as possible in order to uniformly weigh the above-mentioned heterogeneous effects. As a result, these prices reflect the value a society attaches to the caused effects, enabling the decision maker to form a statement about the net social welfare effects of a project. |
+ | |||
+ | == Relevance == |
||
+ | Knowledge about [[Economic tools|economic models/tools]] such as the social cost-benefit analysis can help the urban planner to systematically survey all the relevant (socio-economic) impact caused by an urban development and security threats. This insight will help the responsible urban planners to make the best choices from an socio-economic point of view. |
||
== The null hypothesis == |
== The null hypothesis == |
||
Line 6: | Line 9: | ||
== Measured impacts == |
== Measured impacts == |
||
− | The social cost-benefit analysis calculates the direct ([[Primary economic impact|primary]]), indirect ([[Secondary economic impact|secondary]]) and external effects: |
+ | The social cost-benefit analysis calculates the direct ([[Primary economic impact|primary]]), indirect ([[Secondary economic impact|secondary]]) and external effects: [[File:Playtime construction.JPG|thumb|Construction site]] |
* Direct effects are the costs and benefits that can be directly linked to the owners/users of the project properties (e.g., the users and the owner of a building or highway). |
* Direct effects are the costs and benefits that can be directly linked to the owners/users of the project properties (e.g., the users and the owner of a building or highway). |
||
Line 14: | Line 17: | ||
* [[External effects]] are the costs and benefits that cannot be passed on to any existing market because they relate to issues like the environment (noise, emission of CO2 etc.), safety (traffic, external security) and nature (biodiversity, dehydration etc.). |
* [[External effects]] are the costs and benefits that cannot be passed on to any existing market because they relate to issues like the environment (noise, emission of CO2 etc.), safety (traffic, external security) and nature (biodiversity, dehydration etc.). |
||
− | The model engineers try to quantify and |
+ | The model engineers try to quantify and monetise as much effects as possible. Effects that cannot be monetised are presented in such a way that they can be compared. This way, policy-makers can include these effects in their final judgement if an urban planning project (or a particular variation) is worth investing in. The method of monetising effects can also influence the outcome of a social cost-benefit analysis and predictions will always remain uncertain. Therefore, the results of a social cost-benefit analysis are not absolute. Nevertheless, it is a sufficient instrument to investigate the strong and weak points of the different alternatives. |
== Results of a social cost-benefit analysis == |
== Results of a social cost-benefit analysis == |
||
Line 24: | Line 27: | ||
# ''Presentation of the uncertainties and risks''. A social cost-benefit analysis has several methods to take economic risks and uncertainties into account. The policy decision should be based on calculated risk. |
# ''Presentation of the uncertainties and risks''. A social cost-benefit analysis has several methods to take economic risks and uncertainties into account. The policy decision should be based on calculated risk. |
||
− | == |
+ | ==Value of a statistical life (VASL)== |
+ | A cost-benefit analysis can help to determine if a certain security measure designed to reduce the risk of death is worthwhile from an economic perspective. In order to do this, one needs to determine the costs of the specific measure, how many lives statistically (or in probability terms) are affected, and, finally, the (monetary) value of preventing a lethal fatality (the Value of a Statistical Life). The cost of preventing a lethal fatality can subsequently be compared with societal value of a statistical life (see example below). |
||
+ | |||
+ | Note that VASL is no the value being placed on a life. It is just another way of expressing what a society is prepared to pay to mitigate a certain risk, and should not be confused with the value society might put on the life of a real person, for example in court<ref> For more information on this subject, see e.g.:Ashenfelter, O. (2006): Measuring the Value of a Statistical Life: Problems and Prospects. NBER Working Paper Series. No. 11916. Online: http://www.nber.org/papers/w11916.pdf?new_window=1.</ref>. |
||
+ | |||
+ | Case example: dedicated surveillance on location |
||
+ | {{quote|A paper by Stewart and Mueller (2008)<ref>Stewart, M.G., J. Mueller (2008): A risk and cost-benefit assessment of United States aviation security measures. Springer Science.</ref> performed a cost-benefit analysis of two aviation security measures, one of them the Federal Air Marshal Service. They conclude that even if the Air Marshal surveillance prevents one 9/11 replication each decade, the $900 million annual spending on Air Marshal Service fails a cost-benefit analysis at an annual estimated cost of $180 million per life saved (compared to a societal willingness to pay to save a life of $1 - $10 million per saved life).}} |
||
+ | |||
+ | == Risk of double counting == |
||
The impact of an urban development project can be measured in two or more ways. For example, when an improved highway reduces travel time, the value of real estate property in areas served by the highway will be enhanced. The increase in property values due to the project is a possible way to measure the benefits of a project. But if the increased property values are included, it is unnecessary to include the value of the time saved by the improvement in the highway. Unnecessary, because the value of the real estate property went up because of improvement in reach ability, so including both the increase in property values and the time saving reduction, would lead to a double counting. |
The impact of an urban development project can be measured in two or more ways. For example, when an improved highway reduces travel time, the value of real estate property in areas served by the highway will be enhanced. The increase in property values due to the project is a possible way to measure the benefits of a project. But if the increased property values are included, it is unnecessary to include the value of the time saved by the improvement in the highway. Unnecessary, because the value of the real estate property went up because of improvement in reach ability, so including both the increase in property values and the time saving reduction, would lead to a double counting. |
||
+ | |||
− | |||
− | == |
+ | ==Limits of economic methods == |
− | [[Moral aspects of socio economic methods| |
+ | Like any other economic tool, social cost-benefit analysis has its [[Limits of economic analysis|fundamental and methodological limits]]. In addition, [[Moral aspects of socio economic methods|moral aspects of socio-economic methods]] are a fundamental aspect of any economic decision. The public interest is more than the difference between financial costs and benefits, and includes ethical aspects like balance between individual and collective interests, the intrinsic value of nature and human life, the (universal) right to live in a secure environment, and so on. |
== Related subjects == |
== Related subjects == |
||
− | Urban planning processes employ a host of economic tools/models |
+ | Urban planning processes employ a host of other economic tools/models: |
+ | * [[Input-output analysis|Input-output analysis]] |
||
+ | * [[Economic Impact Study|Economic impact study]] |
||
+ | * [[Business case|Business case]] |
||
+ | * [[Other economic tools|Other economic tools]] |
||
+ | * [[Economic tools|Economic tools]] |
||
+ | |||
+ | See also the clickable map below: |
||
<imagemap> |
<imagemap> |
||
Line 52: | Line 70: | ||
{{references}} |
{{references}} |
||
− | |||
− | = MAP = |
||
− | <websiteFrame> |
||
− | website=http://securipedia.eu/cool/index.php?wiki=securipedia.eu&concept=Social_cost-benefit_analysis |
||
− | height=1023 |
||
− | width=100% |
||
− | border=0 |
||
− | scroll=auto |
||
− | align=middle |
||
− | </websiteFrame> |
||
− | |||
− | <headertabs/> |
||
⚫ |
Latest revision as of 00:05, 20 January 2018
Social cost-benefit analysis is a systematic and cohesive economic tool(method) to survey all the impacts caused by an urban development project[1]. It comprises not just the financial effects (investment costs, direct benefits like tax and fees, et cetera), but all the social effects, like: pollution, safety, indirect (labour) market, legal aspects, et cetera. The main aim of a social cost-benefit analysis is to attach a price to as many effects as possible in order to uniformly weigh the above-mentioned heterogeneous effects. As a result, these prices reflect the value a society attaches to the caused effects, enabling the decision maker to form a statement about the net social welfare effects of a project.
Contents
Relevance
Knowledge about economic models/tools such as the social cost-benefit analysis can help the urban planner to systematically survey all the relevant (socio-economic) impact caused by an urban development and security threats. This insight will help the responsible urban planners to make the best choices from an socio-economic point of view.
The null hypothesis
A major advantage of a social cost-benefit analysis is that it enables investors to systematically and cohesively compare different project alternatives. Hence, these alternatives will not just be compared intrinsically, but will also be set against the "null alternative hypothesis". This hypothesis describes "the most likely" scenario development in case a project will not be executed. Put differently, investments on a smaller scale will be included in the null alternative hypothesis in order to make a realistic comparison in a situation without "huge" investments.
Measured impacts
The social cost-benefit analysis calculates the direct (primary), indirect (secondary) and external effects:
- Direct effects are the costs and benefits that can be directly linked to the owners/users of the project properties (e.g., the users and the owner of a building or highway).
- Indirect effects are the costs and benefits that are passed on to the producers and consumers outside the market with which the project is involved (e.g., the owner of a bakery nearby the new building, or a business company located near the newly planned highway).
- External effects are the costs and benefits that cannot be passed on to any existing market because they relate to issues like the environment (noise, emission of CO2 etc.), safety (traffic, external security) and nature (biodiversity, dehydration etc.).
The model engineers try to quantify and monetise as much effects as possible. Effects that cannot be monetised are presented in such a way that they can be compared. This way, policy-makers can include these effects in their final judgement if an urban planning project (or a particular variation) is worth investing in. The method of monetising effects can also influence the outcome of a social cost-benefit analysis and predictions will always remain uncertain. Therefore, the results of a social cost-benefit analysis are not absolute. Nevertheless, it is a sufficient instrument to investigate the strong and weak points of the different alternatives.
Results of a social cost-benefit analysis
The result of a social cost-benefit analysis are:
- An integrated way of comparing the different effects. All relevant costs and benefits of the different project implementations (alternatives) are identified and monetized as far as possible. Effects that cannot be monetized are described and quantified as much as possible.
- Attention for the distribution of costs and benefits. The benefits of a project do not always get to the groups bearing the costs. A social cost-benefit analysis gives insight in who bears the costs and who derives the benefits.
- Comparison of the project alternatives. A social cost-benefit analysis is a good method to show the differences between project alternatives and provides information to make a well informed decision.
- Presentation of the uncertainties and risks. A social cost-benefit analysis has several methods to take economic risks and uncertainties into account. The policy decision should be based on calculated risk.
Value of a statistical life (VASL)
A cost-benefit analysis can help to determine if a certain security measure designed to reduce the risk of death is worthwhile from an economic perspective. In order to do this, one needs to determine the costs of the specific measure, how many lives statistically (or in probability terms) are affected, and, finally, the (monetary) value of preventing a lethal fatality (the Value of a Statistical Life). The cost of preventing a lethal fatality can subsequently be compared with societal value of a statistical life (see example below).
Note that VASL is no the value being placed on a life. It is just another way of expressing what a society is prepared to pay to mitigate a certain risk, and should not be confused with the value society might put on the life of a real person, for example in court[2].
Case example: dedicated surveillance on location
A paper by Stewart and Mueller (2008)[3] performed a cost-benefit analysis of two aviation security measures, one of them the Federal Air Marshal Service. They conclude that even if the Air Marshal surveillance prevents one 9/11 replication each decade, the $900 million annual spending on Air Marshal Service fails a cost-benefit analysis at an annual estimated cost of $180 million per life saved (compared to a societal willingness to pay to save a life of $1 - $10 million per saved life).
Risk of double counting
The impact of an urban development project can be measured in two or more ways. For example, when an improved highway reduces travel time, the value of real estate property in areas served by the highway will be enhanced. The increase in property values due to the project is a possible way to measure the benefits of a project. But if the increased property values are included, it is unnecessary to include the value of the time saved by the improvement in the highway. Unnecessary, because the value of the real estate property went up because of improvement in reach ability, so including both the increase in property values and the time saving reduction, would lead to a double counting.
Limits of economic methods
Like any other economic tool, social cost-benefit analysis has its fundamental and methodological limits. In addition, moral aspects of socio-economic methods are a fundamental aspect of any economic decision. The public interest is more than the difference between financial costs and benefits, and includes ethical aspects like balance between individual and collective interests, the intrinsic value of nature and human life, the (universal) right to live in a secure environment, and so on.
Related subjects
Urban planning processes employ a host of other economic tools/models:
See also the clickable map below:
Other related subjects:
Footnotes and references
- ↑ In the Netherlands, conducting a social cost-benefit analysis is mandatory for major infrastructure projects.
- ↑ For more information on this subject, see e.g.:Ashenfelter, O. (2006): Measuring the Value of a Statistical Life: Problems and Prospects. NBER Working Paper Series. No. 11916. Online: http://www.nber.org/papers/w11916.pdf?new_window=1.
- ↑ Stewart, M.G., J. Mueller (2008): A risk and cost-benefit assessment of United States aviation security measures. Springer Science.