Difference between revisions of "Limits of economic analysis"

From Securipedia
Jump to navigation Jump to search
 
(17 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
[[Category:Economic]][[Category:Ethical]]
 
[[Category:Economic]][[Category:Ethical]]
   
  +
= {{PAGENAME}} =
 
[[File:ae.png|25px|right|This is a page providing background in a specific field of expertise]] [[Economic tools]] facilitate in the preparation of a robust urban plan and can help with making a city more resilient against crime & terrorism, but there are also some fundamental and methodological '''limits of economic analysis/tools''' that have to be considered.
+
[[File:ae.png|25px|right|This is a page providing background in a specific field of expertise]] [[Economic tools]] facilitate in the preparation of a robust urban plan and can help with making a city more resilient against crime and terrorism, but there are also some fundamental and methodological '''limits of economic analysis/tools''' that have to be considered.
   
 
==Consequential focus==
 
==Consequential focus==
Economic tools such as the [[Social cost-benefit analysis|cost-benefit analysis]] assume a basic rationale that things are worth investing in if the positive effects outweigh the negative ones. This imposes an evaluation of costs and benefits with a focus on the consequences of the respective decisions<ref>Sen, A.K.(2000). The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 936.</ref>. However, this guidance by consequences can violate fundamental rights (such as civil rights) and is irrespective of
+
Economic tools such as the [[Social cost-benefit analysis|cost-benefit analysis]] assume a basic rationale that things are worth investing in if the positive effects outweigh the negative ones. This imposes an evaluation of costs and benefits with a focus on the consequences of the respective decisions<ref>Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 936.</ref>. However, this guidance by consequences can violate fundamental rights (such as civil rights) and is irrespective of actions based on their “rightness” or “duty/obligation”.
  +
actions based on their “rightness” or “duty/obligation”.
 
  +
An example:
  +
The aim of a social cost-benefit analysis is to select the project with the highest social cost-benefit ratio that will lead to a maximisation of wealth for society. But what if the planned expansion of a new airport will indeed increase the (economic) well being of a region, but at the same time will significantly reduce the quality of life for people living close to the airport? Put differently, does a society have the obligation to protect the rights of all its citizens (including future citizens) or only the present majority?
   
 
==Assumed complete knowledge==
 
==Assumed complete knowledge==
Economic analysis tend to assume “completeness of knowledge” of all the effects and corresponding weigths<ref>Ibid. p.939</ref>. Apart from the fact that the used techniques are an estimate rather than a precise measurement, there is the risk in daily practice that in search of completeness the economic analysis results in judgements that are without justification, which, according to Sen (2000, p.941) results in ignoring “the less exactly measured consequences or less clearly agreed values, even though they may be extremely important..”<ref>Ibid, p.941</ref>. Examples of these often ignored consequences are the environmental effects, the effects on quality of life, etc.
+
Economic analysis tends to assume “completeness of knowledge” of all the effects and corresponding weights<ref>Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 939.</ref>. Apart from the fact that the used techniques are an estimate rather than a precise measurement, there is the risk in daily practice that in search of completeness the economic analysis results in judgements that are without justification, which, according to Sen<ref>Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 941.</ref>,(an Indian economist and a Nobel laureate who has made contributions to welfare economics, social choice theory, economic and social justice, economic theories of famines, and indexes of the measure of well-being of citizens of developing countries) results in ignoring “the less exactly measured consequences or less clearly agreed values, even though they may be extremely important”<ref>Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 941.</ref>. Examples of these often ignored consequences are the environmental effects, the effects on quality of life, etc.
   
  +
An example:
==Dominating market thinking==
 
  +
It is common practice for social cost-benefit analysis to place a monetary value on human life, for example, when assessing safety measures against terrorism or road safety. The question is, however, if it is possible to adequately value a human life based on a market valuation system.
Economic effects are principally valuated according to the market mechanism. However, for a lot of goods (public goods, the environment, etc.) and specific type of effects (e.g. external effects) there are no existing markets. As a result, market valuation only admits a narrow class of values, neglecting, for example, distributional issues (the poor versus the rich) and changes in values as a result of changes in the urban environment.
 
  +
 
==Dominant market thinking==
 
Economic effects are principally valued according to the market mechanism. However, for a lot of goods (public goods, the environment, etc.) and specific type of effects (e.g. external effects) there exist no markets. As a result, market valuation only admits a narrow class of values, neglecting, for example, distributional issues and changes in values as a result of changes in the urban environment.
   
 
== Normative claim==
 
== Normative claim==
Line 21: Line 26:
 
*[[Economic tools]]
 
*[[Economic tools]]
 
*[[Economic|Economic main page]]
 
*[[Economic|Economic main page]]
Categories of economic impact:
 
* [[Primary economic impact]]
 
* [[Secondary economic impact]]
 
* [[External effects]]
 
 
The four subdimensions:
 
*[[Economic impact of urban planning]]
 
*[[Economic impact of security threats]]
 
*[[Economic impact of security measures]]
 
*[[The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|Economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour]]
 
   
 
{{references}}
 
{{references}}
 
= MAP =
 
 
<websiteFrame>
 
website=http://securipedia.eu/cool/index.php?concept=<replace with pagename>
 
width=100%
 
border=0
 
scroll=auto
 
align=middle
 
</websiteFrame>
 
 
<headertabs/>
 

Latest revision as of 16:35, 23 October 2013


This is a page providing background in a specific field of expertise

Economic tools facilitate in the preparation of a robust urban plan and can help with making a city more resilient against crime and terrorism, but there are also some fundamental and methodological limits of economic analysis/tools that have to be considered.

Consequential focus

Economic tools such as the cost-benefit analysis assume a basic rationale that things are worth investing in if the positive effects outweigh the negative ones. This imposes an evaluation of costs and benefits with a focus on the consequences of the respective decisions[1]. However, this guidance by consequences can violate fundamental rights (such as civil rights) and is irrespective of actions based on their “rightness” or “duty/obligation”.

An example: The aim of a social cost-benefit analysis is to select the project with the highest social cost-benefit ratio that will lead to a maximisation of wealth for society. But what if the planned expansion of a new airport will indeed increase the (economic) well being of a region, but at the same time will significantly reduce the quality of life for people living close to the airport? Put differently, does a society have the obligation to protect the rights of all its citizens (including future citizens) or only the present majority?

Assumed complete knowledge

Economic analysis tends to assume “completeness of knowledge” of all the effects and corresponding weights[2]. Apart from the fact that the used techniques are an estimate rather than a precise measurement, there is the risk in daily practice that in search of completeness the economic analysis results in judgements that are without justification, which, according to Sen[3],(an Indian economist and a Nobel laureate who has made contributions to welfare economics, social choice theory, economic and social justice, economic theories of famines, and indexes of the measure of well-being of citizens of developing countries) results in ignoring “the less exactly measured consequences or less clearly agreed values, even though they may be extremely important”[4]. Examples of these often ignored consequences are the environmental effects, the effects on quality of life, etc.

An example: It is common practice for social cost-benefit analysis to place a monetary value on human life, for example, when assessing safety measures against terrorism or road safety. The question is, however, if it is possible to adequately value a human life based on a market valuation system.

Dominant market thinking

Economic effects are principally valued according to the market mechanism. However, for a lot of goods (public goods, the environment, etc.) and specific type of effects (e.g. external effects) there exist no markets. As a result, market valuation only admits a narrow class of values, neglecting, for example, distributional issues and changes in values as a result of changes in the urban environment.

Normative claim

In theory, economic science does not presuppose a policy preference and the outcomes of a cost-benefit analysis or economic impact study is not the decisive step in the decision-making process. In practice, however, both economists and the public decision makers have to be very careful not to regard the economic analysis as the final/normative step in the decision-making process, and to reduce the multidimensional realm of reality to a financial and market value based model of reality.

Related subjects

Footnotes and references

  1. Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 936.
  2. Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 939.
  3. Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 941.
  4. Sen, A.K.(2000): The discipline of cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies 29(S2): p. 941.