Difference between revisions of "The economics of crime"
(44 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
+ | [[Category:Economic]] |
||
− | = The economics of crime = |
||
− | Economics of crime deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures. |
+ | [[File:ae.png|25px|right|This is a page providing background in a specific field of expertise]]'''Economics of crime''' deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures. |
+ | Insight in the impact of incentives on criminal and terrorist behaviour is of major relevance for urban planners since criminals and terrorists will most likely alter their behaviour in reaction to taken security measures in order to fulfil their goals. |
||
⚫ | |||
== Behaviour of criminals == |
== Behaviour of criminals == |
||
− | The standard economic model of crime is introduced in 1968 by Nobel Prize laureate Gary Becker<ref name="ftn55"> Becker, G. (1968) |
+ | The standard economic model of crime is introduced in 1968 by Nobel Prize laureate Gary Becker<ref name="ftn55"> Becker, G. (1968): Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy. No. 76, p. 169-217.</ref>. His work radically changed the way of thinking about criminal behaviour by demonstrating that not so much mental illness and social oppressions, but individual rationality, determines whether a person engages in criminal activities or not. Becker's rational criminal decides whether or not to commit crimes based on a cost-benefit analysis aimed at maximizing utility<ref>Utility is a representation of preferences over some set of goods and services(Source: Wikipedia).</ref>. |
− | Based on the assumption that the individual preferences are constant, |
+ | Based on the assumption that the individual preferences are constant, rational choice theory<ref>Rational choice theory is a framework for understanding and often formally modelling social and economic behaviour. It is at the heart of modern economic theory and in the disciplines contiguous to economics, such as some parts of political science, decision theory, law and history that have adopted the theory as their model of decision making (Source: Ulen, T. S. (1999). ''Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics''). Rational Choice Theory can be considered as an attempt to explain all (conforming and deviant) social phenomenon in terms of how self-interest individuals make choices under the influence of their preferences (Source: Business Dictionary.com).</ref> can be used to predict how changes in the probability and severity of sanctions and in various socio-economic factors may effect the amount of crime<ref name="ftn56"> Source: Eide, E. (1999): Economic of Criminal Behavior.</ref>. The types of gains depend on the type of crime and the individual criminal: some are monetary gains, others are physical. Examples of cost are material cost, psychic cost (guilt, anxiety, fear), expected punishment cost and [[Opportunity cost|opportunity cost]].<ref name="ftn56"></ref> |
+ | ===Limits to the rational choice theory=== |
||
− | Within the scientific world, there is discussion if the economic model of crime is in conflict with other theories of crime. This debate is centred around the question how rational a criminal really is<ref name="ftn58">See, e.g. theories of bounded rationality.</ref>. Several authors wonder if people indeed have sufficient information to calculate the outcomes of their acting. Others stress out that the motivation, identity and surroundings of a criminal also are important factors that explain criminal behaviour<ref name="ftn59"> See, e.g. Ulen, T.S. (1999). ''Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics'' (p. 800); or: Eide, E. (1999); Winden, F. van de, E. Ash (2009).</ref>. |
||
+ | Within the scientific world, there is an ongoing debate if the economic model of crime is in conflict with other theories of crime and fully explain criminal decision-making. This debate was initially centred around the question how rational a criminal really is, referring to the fact that the 'rationality' criminals possess is actually 'bounded' or 'limited'<ref name=Wright>Wright et al. (2005): The Foreground Dynamics of Street Robbery in Britain. Advance Access Publication, 14 June 2005.</ref>. Criticisers of rational choice theory wonder if potential offenders indeed have sufficient information to calculate the outcomes of their acting, and others stress out that the motivation, identity and surroundings of a criminal are also important factors that explain criminal behaviour<ref name="ftn59"> See, e.g. Ulen, T.S. (1999): Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics (p. 800); Winden, F., and E. Ash (2012): On The Behavioral Economics of Crime. Review of Law & Economics 8, 181-210; Wright et al. (2005): The Foreground Dynamics of Street Robbery in Britain. Advance Access Publication</ref>. They underpin this with the example of an individual who lives a certain 'hedonistic' life style (e.g. a member of an urban street gang or a drug addict), and hence will unlikely consider a legitimate job since such a person does not only needs 'fast cash', but also has a reputation to uphold<ref>"In part, this helps to explain why street robberies often appear so irrational in the sense that they net little cash relative to the lengthy prison sentences that can follow." Source: Wright et al. (2005), p.13</ref>. |
||
− | + | As a result of the above mentioned debate, more recent economic approaches are based on the behavioural approach, which proposes a decision model comprising cognitive and emotional decision systems. According to this approach, a criminal is not irrational but rather ˜ecologically rational, outfitted with evolutionary conserved decision modules adapted for survival in the human ancestral environment (Winden and Ash, 2009)<ref name="ftn60"> Source: Winden, F. van de, E. Ash (2009): On the Behavioral Economics of Crime. Center for Research in Experimental Economics and political Decision-making (CREED). University of Amsterdam.</ref>. |
|
== Socio-economic causes of crime == |
== Socio-economic causes of crime == |
||
− | Since the 1970s, economists contributed in explaining and validating the traditional socio-economic determinants of crime such as unemployment, education, inequality, social networks, age and socio-economic background. Based on Buonanno's (2003)<ref name="ftn61"> Buananno, P. (2003) |
+ | Since the 1970s, economists contributed in explaining and validating the traditional socio-economic determinants of crime such as unemployment, education, inequality, social networks, age and socio-economic background. Based on Buonanno's (2003)<ref name="ftn61"> Buananno, P. (2003): The Socioeconomic Determinants of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan.</ref> review of the economic contributions, it can be concluded that crime is closely related to: |
+ | [[File:Riots 3.jpg|thumb|Riots often are accompanied with vandalism, such as arson]] |
||
* poverty, |
* poverty, |
||
* social exclusion, |
* social exclusion, |
||
Line 22: | Line 24: | ||
* other economic and social factors. |
* other economic and social factors. |
||
− | Although the relationship between crime and unemployment is not unambiguous and unclear<ref name="ftn61"></ref>, a study by Lochner and Moretti (2001)<ref name="ftn63"> Lochner, L. and E. Moretti (2001) |
+ | Although the relationship between crime and unemployment is not unambiguous and unclear<ref name="ftn61"></ref>, a study by the economists Lochner and Moretti (2001)<ref name="ftn63"> Lochner, L. and E. Moretti (2001): The effect of education on crime: evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. NBER Working Paper no. 8605. In: Buananno, P. (2003): The Socioeconomic Determinantes of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan, p. 20-21.</ref> argues that the impact of education on crime is so strong, that, in fact, 1 percent increase in high school completion rate of all men ages 20-60 would save the United States as much as USD 1.4 billion per year in reduced cost from crime incurred by victims and society at large (p.31). The economists Glaeser and Sacerdote (1999)<ref name="ftn64"> Glaeser, E.L. and B. Sacerdote (1999): Why is there more crime in cities?. Journal of Political Economy, No 111, pp. 507-548. In: Ibid.</ref>, find that crime rates in big cities in the US are much higher than in small cities or rural areas due to the fact that families are much less intact in cities (45 percent), there are higher benefit levels in cities (26 percent) and lower probability of arrest (12 percent). It has to be noted, however, that the economic crime models focus more on property crimes such as theft, and not on crimes like murder and rape<ref name="ftn65"> Hall, A. (2007): Socio-Economic Theories of Crime. Capella University.</ref>. |
== Interaction of anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour == |
== Interaction of anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour == |
||
Line 28: | Line 30: | ||
=== Crime displacement === |
=== Crime displacement === |
||
− | '''Crime displacement''' is the relocation of crime from one place, time, target, |
+ | '''Crime displacement''' is the relocation of crime from one place, time, target, offence, or tactic to another as a result of some crime prevention initiative (Guerette, 2009)<ref name="ftn66"> Source: Guerette, R.T. (2009): Analyzing Crime Displacement and Diffusion. Tool Guide No. 10.</ref>. At worst, crime displacement can lead to more harmful consequences, for example, when there is a shift to more serious offences or to similar offences that have more serious consequences. However, according to the American criminologist Guerette, displacement can in some cases still provide some benefit. Crime, for example, can become less serious (e.g. petty thefts in stead of robbery), lower in volume and less impactful on the community due to a |
#redistribution of the concentration of crime, |
#redistribution of the concentration of crime, |
||
#the relocation of the crime or a |
#the relocation of the crime or a |
||
Line 39: | Line 41: | ||
=== Policy implications === |
=== Policy implications === |
||
− | Guerette (2009) points out that crime displacement and diffusion of benefits have many implications for policing projects, and that any policing project should be well-researched in order to identify the likelihood of displacement and diffusion<ref name="ftn69"> See for more information: [http://www.popcenter.org/ http://www.popcenter.org/]</ref>. |
+ | The American criminologist Guerette (2009) points out that crime displacement and diffusion of benefits have many implications for policing projects, and that any policing project should be well-researched in order to identify the likelihood of displacement and diffusion<ref name="ftn69"> See for more information: [http://www.popcenter.org/ http://www.popcenter.org/]</ref>. |
− | == |
+ | ==Related subjects== |
+ | *[[Economic|Economic main page]] |
||
⚫ | |||
+ | *[[Economic impact]] |
||
+ | **[[Economic impact of urban planning|Economic impact of urban planning]] |
||
+ | **[[Economic impact of security threats]] |
||
+ | **[[Economic impact of security measures|Economic impact of security measures]] |
||
+ | **[[The economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour|Economics of criminal and terrorist behaviour]] |
||
+ | ***Economics of crime |
||
⚫ | |||
+ | *[[Economic tools]] |
||
+ | *[[Economic output]] |
||
⚫ | |||
− | |||
− | = MAP = |
||
− | <websiteFrame> |
||
− | website=http://securipedia.eu/cool/index.php?wiki=securipedia.eu&concept=The_economics_of_crime |
||
− | height=1023 |
||
− | width=100% |
||
− | border=0 |
||
− | scroll=auto |
||
− | align=middle |
||
− | </websiteFrame> |
||
− | |||
− | <headertabs/> |
Latest revision as of 17:07, 10 October 2016
Economics of crime deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures.
Insight in the impact of incentives on criminal and terrorist behaviour is of major relevance for urban planners since criminals and terrorists will most likely alter their behaviour in reaction to taken security measures in order to fulfil their goals.
Contents
Behaviour of criminals
The standard economic model of crime is introduced in 1968 by Nobel Prize laureate Gary Becker[1]. His work radically changed the way of thinking about criminal behaviour by demonstrating that not so much mental illness and social oppressions, but individual rationality, determines whether a person engages in criminal activities or not. Becker's rational criminal decides whether or not to commit crimes based on a cost-benefit analysis aimed at maximizing utility[2].
Based on the assumption that the individual preferences are constant, rational choice theory[3] can be used to predict how changes in the probability and severity of sanctions and in various socio-economic factors may effect the amount of crime[4]. The types of gains depend on the type of crime and the individual criminal: some are monetary gains, others are physical. Examples of cost are material cost, psychic cost (guilt, anxiety, fear), expected punishment cost and opportunity cost.[4]
Limits to the rational choice theory
Within the scientific world, there is an ongoing debate if the economic model of crime is in conflict with other theories of crime and fully explain criminal decision-making. This debate was initially centred around the question how rational a criminal really is, referring to the fact that the 'rationality' criminals possess is actually 'bounded' or 'limited'[5]. Criticisers of rational choice theory wonder if potential offenders indeed have sufficient information to calculate the outcomes of their acting, and others stress out that the motivation, identity and surroundings of a criminal are also important factors that explain criminal behaviour[6]. They underpin this with the example of an individual who lives a certain 'hedonistic' life style (e.g. a member of an urban street gang or a drug addict), and hence will unlikely consider a legitimate job since such a person does not only needs 'fast cash', but also has a reputation to uphold[7].
As a result of the above mentioned debate, more recent economic approaches are based on the behavioural approach, which proposes a decision model comprising cognitive and emotional decision systems. According to this approach, a criminal is not irrational but rather ˜ecologically rational, outfitted with evolutionary conserved decision modules adapted for survival in the human ancestral environment (Winden and Ash, 2009)[8].
Socio-economic causes of crime
Since the 1970s, economists contributed in explaining and validating the traditional socio-economic determinants of crime such as unemployment, education, inequality, social networks, age and socio-economic background. Based on Buonanno's (2003)[9] review of the economic contributions, it can be concluded that crime is closely related to:
- poverty,
- social exclusion,
- wage and income inequality,
- cultural and family background,
- level of education and,
- other economic and social factors.
Although the relationship between crime and unemployment is not unambiguous and unclear[9], a study by the economists Lochner and Moretti (2001)[10] argues that the impact of education on crime is so strong, that, in fact, 1 percent increase in high school completion rate of all men ages 20-60 would save the United States as much as USD 1.4 billion per year in reduced cost from crime incurred by victims and society at large (p.31). The economists Glaeser and Sacerdote (1999)[11], find that crime rates in big cities in the US are much higher than in small cities or rural areas due to the fact that families are much less intact in cities (45 percent), there are higher benefit levels in cities (26 percent) and lower probability of arrest (12 percent). It has to be noted, however, that the economic crime models focus more on property crimes such as theft, and not on crimes like murder and rape[12].
Interaction of anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour
Policy makers, including urban planners, are increasingly taking interest in two types of dynamic interaction effects between anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour. The first type of interaction is called ˜crime displacement" and the other is ˜diffusion of crime".
Crime displacement
Crime displacement is the relocation of crime from one place, time, target, offence, or tactic to another as a result of some crime prevention initiative (Guerette, 2009)[13]. At worst, crime displacement can lead to more harmful consequences, for example, when there is a shift to more serious offences or to similar offences that have more serious consequences. However, according to the American criminologist Guerette, displacement can in some cases still provide some benefit. Crime, for example, can become less serious (e.g. petty thefts in stead of robbery), lower in volume and less impactful on the community due to a
- redistribution of the concentration of crime,
- the relocation of the crime or a
- transfer away from vulnerable groups of the population.
Whether displacement occurs is largely determined by three factors: offender motivation, offender familiarity, and crime opportunity[13]. Career criminals and drug addicts are more likely to continue to act criminal than marginal offenders after a response by anti-crime agents. Furthermore, offenders are more likely to relocate their behaviour to targets, places and times with which they are most familiar with. Finally, the presence of crime opportunities determines when and where displacement occurs.
Diffusion of crime
Diffusion of crime entails the reduction of crime (or other improvements) in areas or ways that are related to the targeted crime prevention efforts, but not targeted by the response itself[13]. For instance, implemented security measures targeting commercial burglary may also achieve an added reduction in shoplifting. As with displacement, diffusion of benefits can occur in many forms. Spatial and target diffusion occurs when areas or other crime targets near the intervention zone also experience a reduction in crime. Temporal diffusion occurs when other time periods experience a reduction in crime, even though the intervention was not applies during those times. The example, mentioned above, is an example of crime type diffusion.
Policy implications
The American criminologist Guerette (2009) points out that crime displacement and diffusion of benefits have many implications for policing projects, and that any policing project should be well-researched in order to identify the likelihood of displacement and diffusion[14].
Related subjects
Footnotes and references
- ↑ Becker, G. (1968): Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy. No. 76, p. 169-217.
- ↑ Utility is a representation of preferences over some set of goods and services(Source: Wikipedia).
- ↑ Rational choice theory is a framework for understanding and often formally modelling social and economic behaviour. It is at the heart of modern economic theory and in the disciplines contiguous to economics, such as some parts of political science, decision theory, law and history that have adopted the theory as their model of decision making (Source: Ulen, T. S. (1999). Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics). Rational Choice Theory can be considered as an attempt to explain all (conforming and deviant) social phenomenon in terms of how self-interest individuals make choices under the influence of their preferences (Source: Business Dictionary.com).
- ↑ 4.0 4.1 Source: Eide, E. (1999): Economic of Criminal Behavior.
- ↑ Wright et al. (2005): The Foreground Dynamics of Street Robbery in Britain. Advance Access Publication, 14 June 2005.
- ↑ See, e.g. Ulen, T.S. (1999): Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics (p. 800); Winden, F., and E. Ash (2012): On The Behavioral Economics of Crime. Review of Law & Economics 8, 181-210; Wright et al. (2005): The Foreground Dynamics of Street Robbery in Britain. Advance Access Publication
- ↑ "In part, this helps to explain why street robberies often appear so irrational in the sense that they net little cash relative to the lengthy prison sentences that can follow." Source: Wright et al. (2005), p.13
- ↑ Source: Winden, F. van de, E. Ash (2009): On the Behavioral Economics of Crime. Center for Research in Experimental Economics and political Decision-making (CREED). University of Amsterdam.
- ↑ 9.0 9.1 Buananno, P. (2003): The Socioeconomic Determinants of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan.
- ↑ Lochner, L. and E. Moretti (2001): The effect of education on crime: evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. NBER Working Paper no. 8605. In: Buananno, P. (2003): The Socioeconomic Determinantes of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan, p. 20-21.
- ↑ Glaeser, E.L. and B. Sacerdote (1999): Why is there more crime in cities?. Journal of Political Economy, No 111, pp. 507-548. In: Ibid.
- ↑ Hall, A. (2007): Socio-Economic Theories of Crime. Capella University.
- ↑ 13.0 13.1 13.2 Source: Guerette, R.T. (2009): Analyzing Crime Displacement and Diffusion. Tool Guide No. 10.
- ↑ See for more information: http://www.popcenter.org/