Difference between revisions of "The economics of crime"

From Securipedia
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Line 1: Line 1:
 
= The economics of crime =
 
= The economics of crime =
Economics of crime deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures.
+
'''Economics of crime''' deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures.
   
 
== Behaviour of criminals ==
 
== Behaviour of criminals ==

Revision as of 10:43, 14 August 2012

The economics of crime

Economics of crime deals with the effect of incentives on criminal behaviour and the possible measures to reduce crime. Economic models not only predict and explain the behaviour of criminals, but can also be used to describe the causes of crime and the dynamic interaction between criminals and anti-crime measures.

Behaviour of criminals

The standard economic model of crime is introduced in 1968 by Nobel Prize laureate Gary Becker[1]. His work radically changed the way of thinking about criminal behaviour by demonstrating that not so much mental illness and social oppressions, but individual rationality, determines whether a person engages in criminal activities or not. Becker's rational criminal decides whether or not to commit crimes based on a cost-benefit analysis aimed at maximizing utility.

Based on the assumption that the individual preferences are constant, Rational choice theory can be used to predict how changes in the probability and severity of sanctions and in various socio-economic factors may effect the amount of crime (Eide, 1999)[2]. The types of gains depend on the type of crime and the individual criminal: some are monetary gains, others are physic. Examples of costs are material costs, psychic costs (guilt, anxiety, fear), expected punishment costs and opportunity costs.[2]

Within the scientific world, there is discussion if the economic model of crime is in conflict with other theories of crime. This debate is centred around the question how rational a criminal really is[3]. Several authors wonder if people indeed have sufficient information to calculate the outcomes of their acting. Others stress out that the motivation, identity and surroundings of a criminal also are important factors that explain criminal behaviour[4].

More recent economic approaches are based on the behavioural approach, which proposes a decision model comprising cognitive and emotional decision systems. According to this approach, a criminal is not irrational but rather ˜ecologically rational, outfitted with evolutionary conserved decision modules adapted for survival in the human ancestral environment (Winden and Ash, 2009)[5].

Socio-economic causes of crime

Since the 1970s, economists contributed in explaining and validating the traditional socio-economic determinants of crime such as unemployment, education, inequality, social networks, age and socio-economic background. Based on Buonanno's (2003)[6] review of the economic contributions, it can be concluded that crime is closely related to:

  • poverty,
  • social exclusion,
  • wage and income inequality,
  • cultural and family background,
  • level of education and,
  • other economic and social factors.

Although the relationship between crime and unemployment is not unambiguous and unclear[6], a study by Lochner and Moretti (2001)[7] argues that the impact of education on crime is so strong, that, in fact, 1 percent increase in high school completion rate of all men ages 20-60 would save the United States as much as USD 1.4 billion per year in reduced costs from crime incurred by victims and society at large (p.31). Glaeser and Sacerdote (1999)[8], find that crime rates in big cities in the US are much higher than in small cities or rural areas due to the fact that families are much less intact in cities (45 percent), there are higher benefit levels in cities (26 percent) and lower probability of arrest (12 percent). With Hall (2007)[9], however, it has to be noted, that the economic crime models focus more on property crimes such as theft, and not on crimes like murder and rape.

Interaction of anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour

Policy makers, including urban planners, are increasingly taking interest in two types of dynamic interaction effects between anti-crime measures and criminal behaviour. The first type of interaction is called ˜crime displacement" and the other is ˜diffusion of crime".

Crime displacement

Crime displacement is the relocation of crime from one place, time, target, offense, or tactic to another as a result of some crime prevention initiative (Guerette, 2009)[10]. At worst, crime displacement can lead to more harmful consequences, for example, when there is a shift to more serious offenses or to similar offences that have more serious consequences. However, according to Guerette, displacement can in some cases still provide some benefit. Crime, for example, can become less serious (e.g. petty thefts in stead of robbery), lower in volume and less impactful on the community due to a

  1. redistribution of the concentration of crime,
  2. the relocation of the crime or a
  3. transfer away from vulnerable groups of the population.

Whether displacement occurs is largely determined by three factors: offender motivation, offender familiarity, and crime opportunity[10]. Career criminals and drug addicts are more likely to continue to act criminal than marginal offenders after a response by anti-crime agents. Furthermore, offenders are more likely to relocate their behaviour to targets, places and times with which they are most familiar with. Finally, the presence of crime opportunities determines when and where displacement occurs.

Diffusion of crime

Diffusion of crime entails the reduction of crime (or other improvements) in areas or ways that are related to the targeted crime prevention efforts, but not targeted by the response itself[10]. For instance, implemented security measures targeting commercial burglary may also achieve an added reduction in shoplifting. As with displacement, diffusion of benefits can occur in many forms. Spatial and target diffusion occurs when areas or other crime targets near the intervention zone also experience a reduction in crime. Temporal diffusion occurs when other time periods experience a reduction in crime, even though the intervention was not applies during those times. The example, mentioned above, is an example of crime type diffusion.

Policy implications

Guerette (2009) points out that crime displacement and diffusion of benefits have many implications for policing projects, and that any policing project should be well-researched in order to identify the likelihood of displacement and diffusion[11].

Related subjects

The economics of criminal behaviour is closely linked to the economics of terrorist behaviour (see clickable map):

Error: Image is invalid or non-existent.

Other related subjects are:

Reference

  1. Becker, G. (1968). Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy. No. 76, p. 169-217.
  2. 2.0 2.1 Source: Eide, E. (1999). Economic of Criminal Behavior.
  3. See, e.g. theories of bounded rationality.
  4. See, e.g. Ulen, T.S. (1999). Rational Choice Theory in Law and Economics (p. 800); or: Eide, E. (1999); Winden, F. van de, E. Ash (2009).
  5. Source: Winden, F. van de, E. Ash (2009). On the Behavioral Economics of Crime. Center for Research in Experimental Economics and political Decision-making (CREED). University of Amsterdam.
  6. 6.0 6.1 Buananno, P. (2003). The Socioeconomic Determinantes of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan.
  7. Lochner, L. and E. Moretti (2001). The effect of education on crime: evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. NBER Working Paper no. 8605. In: Buananno, P. (2003). The Socioeconomic Determinantes of Crime. A Review of the Literature. Working Paper Series, No.63. University of Milan, p. 20-21.
  8. Glaeser, E.L. and B. Sacerdote (1999). Why is there more crime in cities?. Journal of Political Economy, No 111, pp. 507-548. In: Ibid.
  9. Hall, A. (2007). Socio-Economic Theories of Crime. Capella University.
  10. 10.0 10.1 10.2 Source: Guerette, R.T. (2009). Analyzing Crime Displacement and Diffusion. Tool Guide No. 10.
  11. See for more information: http://www.popcenter.org/


MAP

<websiteFrame> website=http://securipedia.eu/cool/index.php?wiki=securipedia.eu&concept=The_economics_of_crime height=1023 width=100% border=0 scroll=auto align=middle </websiteFrame>

<headertabs/>